20 July 2013

问题: Fapiaos and Taxes - Do you want to be a Millionaire?

The popular Western maxim assures the populace two things are certain in this world of ours: death and taxes. Evidently, China is no exception. However, the system (note, I am going to focus specifically on commercial taxation and VAT) is not exactly your garden-variety system. 

According to Black’s Law Dictionary (a source law students love to quote), a tax is a “pecuniary burden laid upon individuals or property owners to support the government...not a voluntary payment or donation, but an enforced contribution, exacted pursuant to legislative authority”. Enter the fapiao (发票). A fapiao is a receipt - an official receipt, that is. In China, the State Administration of Taxation is in charge of tax collection, with the Ministry of Finance as the policy mastermind in the backdrop. And the fapiao is their bid to track tax payments and deter tax evasion. 

Fapiaos also double as state lottery tickets. So get your lucky charms ready. 

One of the first things you notice when you buy something in China is that you pay the number on the price sticker. No [insert your desired percentage here] addition at the cash register. This is not because commercial products are not taxed, but because the prices include the value added tax (VAT). The procedure is as follows: 
Step 1: The business owner purchases a fapiao printer (plus appropriate red-stamped and otherwise marked special fapiao paper) from the local tax authority. In the alternative, the business owner can print fixed amount prepaid fapiaos. In this latter case, the standard amounts are fapiaos for 20 RMB and 100 RMB. The business owner can then liberally round your purchase total to the nearest multiple of 20 and hand you your own starters kit for your fapiao collection. 
Step 2: Following the letter of the law, the business issues a fapiao to the consumer for all business transactions at the time of purchase.
Step 3: Once the prepaid fapiaos have run out or -for those proud owners of fapiao printers- the official paper has been all used up, time to call up the local tax authority and respectively, either pre-pay some more taxes or report and pay taxes . Rinse and repeat. 
Simple. However, the pitfalls in this procedure should be evident. To start (and this is not endemic only to China), business owners will look to avoid paying VAT on the transaction. Essentially, no fapiao, no need for the business to report and pay taxes; courtesy of the government, they’ll keep the VAT amount for themselves. The onus falls on the customer. As an additional detail to Step 2 above, in the minutia of the letter of the law, all businesses are required to produce a receipt at the customer’s request at the time of purchase. 

So, the authorities undertake to give customers incentives. And how better to give an incentive than to make each purchase a gamble hope for a cash windfall? Because, as I mentioned above, fapiaos are lottery tickets, complete with their own scratch-to-win box directly on the receipt. It’s ingenious, a Machiavellian turn-of-force that harnesses our self-interest and that intangible rush of hope-fueled adrenaline we get when we play the game. 

And for those customers having a hard time getting their quasi-lottery ticket: if the business owner is unable to produce a valid invoice, you have your chance to play whistle-blower, refuse to pay and call the national tax authority’s hotline at 12366. 

Merging back to the nature of the tax system, if the potential to win millions is not enough of an incentive to ask for that fapiao, there is also the detail that to claim business-related expenses, companies need to provide the tax authority with the original fapiaos. Thus, for any audit-related tax and expense deduction endeavours, fapiaos are mandatory. 

As a closing statement, heed the following warning: make sure that if you are getting a fapiao for tax reduction, the fapiao is issued for the right type of service and made out to the correctly-spelled company name. Otherwise, though you can scratch-and-(maybe)-win all you want, but when it comes time to be reimbursed by your employer for that tai gui kao ya dinner, you’re going to be out of luck. 

KEYWORDS: taxes, fapiao, lottery, Ministry of Finance, VAT

03 July 2013

问题: Anti-Bribery and Guanxi - No Red Envelopes Please

There is an almost unanimous consensus (see your favorite how-to-do-business-in-china book or talk to the suited 老外on the streets of Beijing) that cultivating relationships is the kernel of any business venture in China. It’s called guanxi, key component of Chinese social culture with a practice dating back into the annals of history. 

The concept alludes to the Confucian (yes, him again – just as the West venerates the Athenian philosophers and credits them with the essence of Western thought, the Chinese hold a special place in their hearts for 孔子师傅) structural idea of a “government of the people” as opposed to the more legalist “government of laws”. There is no denying that maintaining good relationships with regulators and officials is crucial to any enterprise, in China and elsewhere. However, for some reason, guanxi is oft misinterpreted. The result of this misunderstanding: a belief that bribery and corruption are the norm in China and a required rite of passage for any foreign investor.

Bribery is not “the way things are done in China”. Bribery is bad. It is illegal and can put both nationals and foreigners away for a long-time. The media is rampant with horror stories of foreign companies that have run afoul of anti-bribery and anti-corruption legislation (the Rio Tinto fiasco put away Stern Hu, Australian citizen, for a seven year prison term on a bribery charge, one of the harshest sentences handed down to a foreign executive of a multinational corporation). Yes, maybe giving a local official in a second-tier/third-tier city a red envelope might yield short-term results – a relaxation of the stringent requirements for the establishment of a WFOE, for example – but this type of personal guanxi will not contribute to a stable long-term future. The reach of the national government – in the form of required audits and the like – is not to be underestimated. 

Within China, anti-bribery regulation is outlined in China’s Criminal Law (CCL). Convictions of bribery, thanks to Xi Jinping’s noble quest to fight corruption, are proliferating. The agencies mustered in this witch hunt are spearheaded by the Anti-Bribery and Embezzlement section of the People’s Procuratorate Office, with aid from the Central Committee for Discipline Inspection (CCDI) in the case of tracking down CPC members. In May 2011, the law was extended to include the bribery of foreign officials as well. Art. 164 does not seem like much at first glance – it does not provide for internal control requirements nor does it clearly define any of the critical terms (who exactly is a foreign official remains to be determined). An encouragement for greasing the wheels? No. Art 164’s extraterritorial applications are vast. 

Hypothetical: a WFOE trying to secure a development project in Nigeria has their employee pay a Nigerian local government official a nice vacation. Bribery within the jurisdiction of Art. 164? Yes. And prosecutable in Chinese courts. 

And, of course, foreigners must not forget the wide jurisdictional scope of the US Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) and the new “gold standard” in anti-bribery legislation, the UK Bribery Act 2010. The latter creates a new corporate offence of failing to prevent bribery (s.7), with the sole defense requiring the company to demonstrate (and with a very high bar to meet) that they had adequate procedures in place specifically tailored to preventing bribery. And voluntary disclosure will not save you, in neither the US, the UK or in China. 

Bottom line: best to avoid bribery and follow the law. Always sage advice. 

So, what should be the consensus on guanxi? Mathematically: guanxi ≠ bribery and a more institutional approach is recommended. Enterprises that contribute to local development will likely be recognized and supported by the government. That is the way to cultivate a relationship. Anti-bribery crusades are not disjoint with Chinese social culture and structure, as some would lead you to believe.

Red might be auspicious, but red enveloped are certainly not.

KEYWORDS: Anti-Bribery, Anti-Corruption, Extraterritorial, FCPA, UK Bribery Act 2010, China's Criminal Law, Art. 164

26 June 2013

上课: Crime Rates in China – Political Pressure + Statistics = Cue Elevator Music

Crime rates in China are low. The latest statistics (see UN Office on Drugs and Crime) place China in the arena with Switzerland and Japan, countries which boast some of the best internationally acknowledged public security and domestic order. As of 2012, China’s murder rate was calculated at 1.1 per 100,000 (compare to Switzerland at 0.7, Britain at 1.2 and America at 5.0). The total amount of reported criminal cases in 2010 was 2.6million (in the US there were 10.3million cases that year). Violent crime and property crime show similarly low numbers. Drug trafficking and abuse rates have not shown significant increase from their near non-existent numbers pre-1979. 

Statistics are by nature misleading. How much credence can we really attribute to these glowing reports? The devil is in the details: ‘murder’ does not necessarily include killings which occur in the course of other violent crimes, nor is each one ‘murder’ equivalent to one victim. According to the World Health Organisation, for the 23,300 murders in 2002, there were 38,000 deaths from “homicide-related injuries”. Furthermore, ‘violent crime’ has no set definition and property crimes do not appear to always count towards general crime statistics. So maybe don’t go poking metaphorical bears in China just yet. 

Let’s set the scene. 

China has experienced profound social, political and economic change in the past 30 years. The country is under significant social stress - growing pains if you will – as millions of rural migrant workers flood the cities and the economic gap between rich and poor widens. From what we know of the human condition, these circumstances do not match with the rosy picture painted by the crime statistics. 

Crime in contemporary China is divided into two distinct periods in almost every analysis: Mao Era (1950s-1979) and Post-Deng Xiaoping Reforms Era (1980s-present). Mao Era China was virtually crime-less. Scholars have attributed this to an “institutional suppression of personal economic motivation”. All property which was valuable enough to steal was a state asset and thus the property of the many already and punishments were prohibitive in their severity. Deng Xiaoping’s Reforms in 1978 marked the economic remaking of China. Accompanying these reforms were the introduction of mobility and the reality of unemployment (factors not within contemplation for Mao’s China). The sun had set on the utopian collective and an economically driven society had taken the field. 

The division between the eras is artificially intensified. The government laments the increase in crime, blaming western cultural influences and glorifying the Mao Era days of security and safety. The idea is: crime is a plague from the West. Are not Hollywood movies known for making good guys out of criminals (see: Ocean’s Eleven) and commending a flagrant disregard of the rules? Chinese culture is one of harmony and peace – no one would deliberately seek to commit any offence. Of course, this is a ridiculous notion. Crime obviously existed in China before 1979. And it’s not as if Chinese culture doesn’t glorify the rogue – one of the Four Great Classical Novels (四大名著) is The Water Bandits (水浒传), a Robin Hood-esque tale of outlaws. But this aspiration to go back and adhere to ‘true Chinese values’ of ‘pre-crime’ drives much of the Ministry of Public Security’s goals. 

The first time China submitted its national crime statistics to Interpol was in 1986. Before that, they were considered ‘state secrets’. Crime statistics are the affair of the Ministry of Public Security and reported yearly by the National Bureau of Statistics. Offences are categorized as criminal (more serious) or public security (less serious) cases. The classical problems with official statistics are there: victims’ reporting behaviour varies over time; definitions of crime change; and recording standards are not consistent. Problems are exacerbated by the Ministry’s aspirations. 

In 2010, the Ministry of Public Security demanded at least 85% success rate in murder cases. The result: if their chances for cracking a case don’t look so great, police officers simply do not register the case. Statistics only look at the registered papers, after all. The 1980s-1990s policy of handing out ‘case-cracking’ bonuses also led to under-recording; police officers once again were incentivised not to record hard-to-solve cases. An emphasis on clearing cases also has darker consequences: wrongful conviction and torture to get favourable confessions are serious concerns to scholars and the populace. 

And there we have it: political pressure and a glorious history of crime-free society set a high bar for China. Maybe China’s low crime rates do not tell the whole story. Maybe the statistics are a bit on the utopian side. But we cannot say anything for sure. 

In the end, what matters is that China feels safe. People are not afraid to walk around alone at night and girls don’t clutch desperately at their purses in the crowded Beijing metro. A prevailing sense that public security is high may do more for crime rates than reports tabulating incremental increases.

One RenMin professor joked: let’s not give the people the idea that there is a burgeoning market for crime out there. 

KEYWORDS: Crime in China, Statistics, Policing, Mao Era, Ministry of Public Security, Safety and Public Order

10 June 2013

上课: FDI and BITS – Enter Stage 3, Thank You Barbados

China is a land of contradictions. While one NPC (National People’s Congress) member refers to China as a developing country, a standing judge of the Supreme Court staunchly defines China as a developed nation. The Middle Kingdom flaunts a free market alongside a planned economy. It is both an investor (especially in Africa) and the largest recipient of foreign direct investment in the world after surpassing the USA in 2012.

The first law relating to Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) was the Sino-Foreign Equity Joint Venture (EJV) Law promulgated in 1979, when China officially opened its doors to the world. Other traditional forms of FDI followed: Wholly-Foreign-Owned Enterprises (WFOE) in 1986, Sino-foreign Co-operative Joint Ventures in 1988. A few years later, new patterns joined the game: Foreign Investment Companies Limited by Shares (FICLS), Holding Investment Companies (HIC), and Build Operation Transfer (BOT)s. 

FDI and Joint Venture Law is a clear demonstration of one of the major themes in Chinese Law: incremental transition. Not only does this area of law speak of the co-existence of prima facie mutually exclusive dichotomies (China standing with one leg in the developed and the other in the developing world), but it also highlights China’s priorities as it slowly opens up. China has gone through three distinct stages of development, most clearly visible in Bilateral Investment Treaties (BIT) she has signed. 

Stage One kicks off in 1982: China signs her first BIT with Sweden (yes, the Swedes – but fear not, lest all my ramblings about the Deutsch be naught, Germany was close behind). This was the era of the traditional patterns for FDI, where the norm was limited liability companies where the Chinese would be able to have a say (for this was the time when the legal climate lacked a Corporate Law and all corporations belonged to the government). China wanted investors really invest in China: no half-built house of cards subject to the whims of the foreign market and no exploitation of China’s labour and natural resources. EJVs required foreign investors to invest a minimum of 25% of the capital (as opposed to most other contemporary systems in developing countries, which set a maximum in order to prevent foreign control). China wanted foreign investors to make efforts in the management of their joint ventures; to be invested in their enterprises. Registered capital, profits and risks were to be divided by equity and no matter what the percentage of investment was covered by the foreign investor, the Chairman of the Board of Directors (the big boss of the EJV), had to be Chinese. All production and operation plans had to be submitted in their intimate entirety to the corresponding administrative authority (a planned economy check by the government). WFOEs – since no Chinese party can participate in the enterprise – were governed by two strict requirements: (1) advanced technology and equipment should be used; and (2) products produced should be marketed outside China. China would benefit through the in-state building and operation of advanced technology. Activate educational thirst for a self-sustainable industrial revolution. 

In Stage One, most BITs advocated negotiation and consultation first and only allowed international ad hoc arbitration if the local court confirmed nationalization or expropriation (read: at the discretion of the Chinese government). 

Stage Two spans 1993-1998, defined by China joining ICSID (International Center for Settlement of Investment Disputes). The laws themselves were changing: no longer was the Chairman of the Board of Directors required to be Chinese – this was to be decided privately by the parties with the only stipulation that if the Chairman was foreign, the Vice-Chairman be Chinese and vice versa. And the big drop: no arbitrary nationalization or expropriation of the joint venture was permitted to the government. Except for “the social public interest”, joint ventures could breathe easy. BITs added provisions: competent courts of the contracting party accepting the investment can settle disputes (before, this was limited to Chinese domestic courts); disputes involving the amount of compensation for expropriation that cannot be settled within six months could now be submitted to ICSID or ad hoc arbitration if the state is not party to ICSID (with the caveat that only disputes involving the amount of compensation for expropriation could be submitted to the ICSID or ad hoc arbitration).

Stage Three is largely marked by reforms to many of the FDI and Joint Venture laws enumerated at the beginning of this essay – all circa 2000 (China having ascended to the WTO effective in 2001). The ascension of China to the WTO is a reoccurring factor in much of the legal reform present in the Chinese system. Trade unions were granted a voice. Raw materials for the joint venture could be purchased both inside and outside of China, according to the principle of fairness and reasonableness. Furthermore, there was no longer a need to file production and operation plans to the Chinese government. The independence of the joint ventures became a factor in law-making.

But Stage Three really begins in 1998 with the signing of the BIT between China and Barbados. This BIT lifted all limitations: all disputes, not just those involving expropriation or nationalization compensation, could be submitted to ICSID and ad hoc tribunals. And while ad hoc tribunal awards are only final and binding as reviewed by domestic Chinese courts, ICSID awards are final and binding with only ICSID itself having the authority to declare the awards non-enforceable. The unspoken shift: Chinese courts delegating some of their power. 

Three stages, a neat depiction of changing Chinese priorities: incremental opening up of the Chinese economy and the acquiescence of the legal system to playing the international legal game (at least as far as disputes go). The BIT with Barbados marked the start of a stage that is still incrementally working towards greater independence for joint ventures and greater protection of foreign enterprises today.

Thank you, Barbados. 

KEYWORDS: FDI, Joint Venture Law, EJV, WFOE, BIT, Incremental Transition, Opening Up, Developed & Developing, WTO, ICSID, ad hoc international tribunals, expropriation, tribunal awards

04 June 2013

问题: Guiding Cases - Selected Wisdom from the Supreme People’s Court

As I have discussed before, China is primarily a civil law country. The law is a body of codified, written rules not determined by judges. However, China is also special. Due to the legal kick-start the country went through in 1979, the laws are patchy and lacking comprehensiveness. Furthermore, broad changes have taken place in China’s social and economic spheres (and are still taking place today) – the system needs an internal mechanism to make up for the fact that laws cannot cover all the new developing social and economic relations.

Xi Jinping, General Secretary of the Communist Party of China Central Committee, for one, is concerned with the efficiency and authority of the judicial system. The list of aspirations is long: efficiency, judicial transparency, judicial justice, improved access to justice…en bref, he wants a China ruled by law. What the system needs is judicial reform and innovation.

Part of the solution: guiding cases. Two questions immediately arise.

One, what are ‘guiding’ cases? They cannot be referenced or cited, nor are they binding on the courts. A head-turner for us disciples of the common law, who live by precedent and incorporate cases into our music in our spare time. These are not common law cases: they are more like a hovering notion for the judges to keep in mind. An advisory opinion that is not an advisory opinion. 

Two, why have guiding cases? Can these really meet Xi Jinping’s lofty goals? In the opinion of Professor Wu Shuchen of Shandong University, yes: “the effect of the guiding cases system…first, significantly limits the discretionary power of judges and effectively avoids the defect of different verdicts for similar cases; second, it significantly reduces the uncertainty and unpredictability of the law.” 

So far, the guiding cases have served to cover particularly prickly areas of the law – they provide general provision for cases that happen frequently enough to warrant guidance but not to such an extent that they rank high on the list of priorities for the NPC. With a heavily backed up legislative, the guiding cases act as a steam-valve. For example: of the four guiding cases released upon the SPC’s initiation of the system in 2001, Shanghai Centaline Property v Tao DeHua addressed disputes arising from “private transactions by passing intermediary” between buyers and the intermediaries in second-hand property transactions. Intermediaries were not allowed to pursue damages for use of information if the buyer could have accessed this information through other legal means. A niche area of the law that the NPC would not be able to prioritize but which needed resolution, as intermediary companies are the de facto way to purchase urban property in China. 

The younger generations of legal scholars are open to this quasi-common law addition to the legal system. After all, the Constitution gives the SPC the power to issue advisory cases. Furthermore, most of these up-and-coming legal scholars have served educational terms in common law countries; the efficiency and dynamic adaptability of using case-law is not lost on them. An active judiciary is not that bad of an idea. 

Sixteen cases have been released so far, and no large legal opposition has formed (apart from a few furrowed eyebrows in the legal literature from the legal purists). Hopefully, at least, guiding cases will promote an environment where the rule of law is victorious and people can settle all their problems by legal means. 

Interested? Check out the catalogue of guiding cases with commentary and legal analysis (yes, in English): https://cgc.law.stanford.edu/

KEYWORDS: Supreme People’s Court, Guiding Cases, Judicial Interpretation, Shanghai Centaline Property v Tao DeHua, NPC


30 May 2013

听一下: The Nine Bronze Cauldrons – the Dings and the First Written Laws

The first Chinese law was the 禹刑 (yu xing), unwritten criminal law of the 21st century B.C. The historical record paints harsh system: any person caught scolding their elder could suffer the death penalty, and treason by one member resulted in the conviction of entire families. The penalties for petty crimes ranged from hard labour to castration and feet amputation. In fact, later accounts allude to the possibility that the early administrations deliberately chose not to put their punishments and penalties into writing, for fear of creating contentiousness amongst their subjects.

Fast forward to 536 B.C. The first Chinese statutory law, 刑鼎 (xing ding) was codified, published and cast into a bronze tripod cauldron (note this is 200-500 years earlier than enactment of the Twelve Tables, the first codified statutory laws of Ancient Rome).

We are in the era of the Warring States, in the midst of the Bronze Age. Enter our protagonist: Yu the Great, first King and controller of the Yellow River flood.

China was a vast and dynamic country, ruled by the whims of the earth, with floods and droughts to rival the capriciousness of the Nile in Egypt. Independent states warred against each other. Then Yu came along, beginning the long reign of the Xia Dynasty when he tamed the Yellow River. From the lands wrestled from the elements, he carved out Nine Provinces and demanded bronze tribute from each. Yu, partial to his legacy, made certain to showcase his power by casting nine tripod cauldrons – previously a religiously reserved form used only for food offerings to the gods – from the bronze he received. In one masterful stroke, Yu appropriated the use of the ding (it is a testimony to the antiquity of this vessel that the character for it actually pictographically resembles it: 鼎); the tripod bronze cauldron that had once been reserved only as a vessel to offer tribute to the gods was now a symbol of power and ultimate authority.

In the political and cultural upheaval that followed his reign, the Nine Tripod Cauldrons became legend. From the measured whims of Yu sprung an entire branch of etiquette. Only an Emperor could flaunt nine dings. Feudal lords, one below on the ladder could amass no more than seven, ministers five and the scholarly gentry three or one. The ding had become a status marker. And so when Yu went to codify his laws, he placed them right on his tribute-cast cauldrons.

The dings survive today. At the door of the JunHe Offices – one of the oldest and most prestigious law firms in China -, two massive dings stand in silent vigil. In the atrium of the MingDe Law building at RenMin University, an intricate ding catches the sunlight reflections of the many bronze murals that decorate the walls. Their legacy is even preserved in the spoken word: to compliment a lawyer, tell them their words are “一言九鼎” (“the weight of nine tripod cauldrons”), i.e. their character is beyond reproach. Yu would have been proud. 

KEYWORDS: Chinese Legal Culture, Chinese History

PLACES: JunHe Law Offices, RenMin University

29 May 2013

问题: The 1930 Chinese Civil Code in the German Tradition

German influence is a recurring theme in the study of Chinese law. Contract law, Foreign Investment Law, IP Law, Company Law…and I do not doubt this pattern shall continue. The interesting question is: why? Entire papers are written on this subject. In an effort to oversimplify and be brief, I will focus on the Chinese Civil Code drafted in 1930.

First, a bit of history. During the late Qing Dynasty, Emperor Guang Xu mandated the formation of a special legislative committee: hand-picked legal experts to draft a brand new civil code for China. The sunset days of the Qing Dynasty were the days of the imperial invasion; after the Opium War in 1840, China was opened to the world by the West. The existing legal system of China was to be re-hauled and ‘modernized’, integrating foreign and domestic practices. In 1928, upon the founding of the National Government of the Republic of China, a legislative council charged with codifying a civil law was formed following Guang Xu’s model.

The civil code that was published in 1930 and still exists in Taiwan today is essentially a copy of the German BGB; cut and pasted from the civil codes of Continental Europe. Mei Zhongxie, a legal scholar from Taiwan, shows that 60-70 % of the provisions in the new civil code are imported from the German BGB, 20-30 % from the Swiss and the rest of the provisions lifted from the civil codes of France, Japan and the Soviet Union. 


Why copy foreign codes? These codes were not suited to Chinese society; they spoke of inspiration rather than a deep insight into Chinese society. The result was a law disconnected from local customs, traditions and philosophy.

The legislative committee looked to the Continental-European system for three primary reasons. One, they saw Europe as the future of China, and so sought to adapt to what they believed the reality of Chinese society would be. China of 1920s was an agricultural society; the legislative committee wanted a legal system for the industrial and commercial society China would transform into. Two, foreign materials were clear while Chinese legal knowledge was scattered. The civil code would have to strike a balance between the effort to simplify the code (so that it could be promulgated in a wide way) with the effort to be thorough (the document still had to be comprehensive); a hurdle the European codes had already jumped. Third, the legislative committee had a deadline to meet. 
Currently, the PRC is looking to reform the Chinese Civil Code. The professors at RenMin University all agree: this time around, the government should not cut corners. If the civil code is to be successful, it must be based on profound theoretical study and broad perspective, requiring practical civil adjudicative experience and a deep insight into actual Chinese society. 

REFERENCES: “From an Integration of Western and Chinese Legal Norms to Comparative Legislation: Codification of the Civil Law of the Republic of China” Zhang Sheng (China Legal Science, Vol. 1, No. 2, May 2013).

KEYWORDS: Chinese Legal Culture, Qing Dynasty, Civil Code, BGB, Germany, Republic of China

27 May 2013

上课: One for All and All for One, the Character of the Chinese System of Law

There are five legal families recognized by legal scholars: the civil law, the common law, Islamic law, Hindu law and Chinese law. Of course, other legal systems are sometimes added to the list – e.g. socialist law – while yet other classifications condense the legal families into just three: civil, common and religious. The modern Chinese law borrows from three legal families – civil, common and Chinese – and so I will attempt to briefly skate over the three here.

The civil law and common law are most easily differentiated when compared based on their sources. The civil law comes from Roman law (The Code of Justinian) and is characterized by laws that are written, codified and not determined by judges. Customs, practical realities – Germanic, ecclesiastical, feudal and local -, and prevailing thought – natural law and legal positivism – meshed with Roman law to form the Continental-European tradition of law. In that sense, it is often referred to as Romano-Germanic law. Civil law draws from abstractions (and thus has an inquisitorial court system – that is, a system where the court is actively involved in ascertaining the facts of a case) and distinguishes substantive rules from procedural rules.


The common law system finds origins in the Norman Conquest of Britain in the 11th century. It is commonly referred to as Anglo-American law. As opposed to the civil law, the common law is a judge-made law. Cases are the primary source of law, acting alongside legislative laws and statutes. Law is based on the rule of stare decisis: the principles and rules established by the court in previous cases are binding (or at least persuasive) on the courts in subsequent similar cases. Furthermore, the court system is an adversarial system, not an inquisitorial one: the court is a neutral arbitrator between the prosecution and the defence. Thus, lawyers play the role of interrogators and judges are understood as the creators of the law. Judges are chosen from the ranks of lawyers, unlike in the civil system where judges follow a separate training regime.

Chinese law refers to the ancient legal tradition of China and other Asian countries which had close relations with China. The ideology defining this legal system is the outcome of Confucian thought: law serves to reinforce roles and as a means of social control. Confucian philosophy strives for harmony, opposing the use of excessive legal coercion and instead advocating education and moral examples.

The modern legal system in China folds together all three of the above systems. Primarily based on the civil system as a result of the codification of law under the Republic of China in 1930, common law principles do find a way into the system. Where the inquisitorial system still reigns in theory, judicial reform has practically instituted an adversarial system in the people’s courts (so that the parties and their lawyers, rather than the judges, take on the active role). The prevalence of the informal legal system – using mediations as a means of solving civil disputes, where personal relationships are paramount – is testimony to Confucian thought.

All for one and one Chinese system for all legal traditions. Now the fundamental question…does it work?

KEYWORDS: Legal Families, Chinese Legal Culture, Civil Law, Common Law, Chinese Law

22 May 2013

上课: The Dark Ages, the Black Abyss or 1949-1978 China

All professors of Chinese Law – or at least those giving a general overview of the system – preface their forays with an allusion to the dark abyss from which the modern Chinese law sprung. 

Okay, so perhaps I am being a bit melodramatic. Constitutional Law and the Law of Marriage did exist between the years of 1949-1978. In fact, Constitutional Law was an active project during those years. The National People’s Congress has enacted four Constitutions since 1949: the 1954 Constitution, the 1975 Constitution and the 1978 Constitution all leading up to the current working Constitution of 1982, which has been amended itself four times (in 1988, 1993, 1998, and 2004). 

However, the legal system itself was essentially outlawed (paradox if there ever was one). Political decisions were not required to comply with the Constitution and government actions were often taken outside areas regulated by the latter. Furthermore, the courts themselves were more puppets up for show than anything else. Legal education and the legal profession were destroyed. Without legal experts or lawyers or judges, there was no one to advocate a rational formal system or, in fact, draft one. 

In 1979, the siege ended and a scramble to set up a functioning legal system initiated the reform and opening up of China. The primary focus was the economy. The method, an organized madness: laws were issued for specific topics and locations, drafted on a trial basis and then redrafted later. Efforts were made to professionalize and rationalize the judiciary and legal profession after nearly thirty years without a formal legal education system. 

The darkness before the birth of the modern legal system has important repercussions. Mediation is an important way to handle civil disputes, a legal education is not a requirement to take the bar, and the legislature, not the Constitution, reigns supreme. 

Let it not be said that legal history is ever irrelevant.

KEYWORDS: Chinese Legal Culture, Chinese History, Constitutional Law, Opening Up